Ang S. James et al. (2000) used two alternative
measures of agency costs. First they take direct agency costs, calculated as
the difference in dollar expenses between a firm with a certain ownership and
management structure and the no agency cost base case firm. This measure
captures excessive expenses including perk consumption. They standardized
expenses by annual sales.
The agency costs of debt have been
widely discussed, but Jensen M. Michael (1986) argue that the benefits of debt
in motivating managers and their organizations to be efficient have been
ignored. Agency theory has also brought the roles of managerial decision rights
and various external and internal monitoring and bonding mechanisms to the
forefront of theoretical discussions and empirical research. Great strides have
been made in demonstrating empirically the role of agency costs in
financial decisions such as to explain the choices of capital structure,
maturity structure, dividend policy, and executive compensation ( Ang S. James
et al, 2000).
Managers with substantial free cash
flow can increase dividends or repurchase stock and thereby pay out current
cash that would otherwise be invested in low return projects or wasted. This
leaves managers with control over the use of future free cash flow, but they
can promise to pay out future cash flows by announcing a permanent increase in
the dividend. Such promises are weak because dividends can be reduced in the
future because of various reasons. The fact that capital markets punish
dividends cuts with large stock price reductions is consistent with the agency
costs of free cash flow.
Debt creation, without retention of the
proceeds of the issue, enables managers to effectively bond their promise to
pay out future cash flows. Thus debt can be an effective substitute for
dividends. By issuing debt in exchange for stock, managers are binding their
promise to pay out future cash flows in a way that cannot be accomplished by
simple dividend increase. In doing so, they give shareholders recipients
of the debt the right to take the firm into bankruptcy court if they do not uphold
their promise to make the interest and principal payments. Thus debt reduces
the agency costs of free cash flow by reducing the cash flow available for
spending at the discretion of managers. These are potential determinant of
capital structure Jensen M. Michael (1986).
Jensen M. Michael (1986) identifies
two types of conflicts. Conflicts between shareholders and manages happen
because managers hold less than 100% of residual claim. Consequently, they do
not retain the entire gain from their profit improvement activities, but they
do bear the entire cost of these activities. For example, managers can invest
less effort in managing firm resources and may be able to transfer firm
resources to their own, personal benefit, e.g. by consuming perquisites such as
corporate jets, plush offices, building empires etc. the managers bears the
entire cost of refraining from these activities but captures only a fraction of
the gain. As a result managers indulge in these pursuits relative to the level
that would maximize firm value. This inefficiency may be reduced; the
larger is the fraction of the firms’ equity owned by the manager.
Holding constant the manager’s absolute
investment in the firm, increase in the fraction of the firm financed by debt
increases the manager’s share of the equity and mitigate the loss from the
conflict between the managers and shareholders. Conflicts between debt holders
and equity holders arise because the debt contract gives equity holders an
incentive to invest sub optimally.
More specifically the debt contract
provides that if investment yields large returns, well above the face value of
the debt, equity holders capture most of the gain. If however the investment
fails, because of limited liability, debt holders bear the consequences. As a
result, equity holders may benefit from going for broke i.e. investing in very
risky projects, even if they are value decreasing. Such investments result in a
decrease in the value of the debt. The loss in value of the equity from the
poor investment can be more than offset by the gain in equity value captured at
the expense of debt holders. Equity holders bear this cost to debt holders,
however, when the debt is issued if the debt holders correctly anticipate
equity holders’ future behavior. In this case, the equity holders receive less
for the debt than they otherwise would.
Thus the cost of the incentive to
invest in value decreasing projects created by debt is borne by the equity
holder who issues the debt. This effect, generally called the asset
substitution effect is an agency cost of debt. Jensen M. Michael (1986) further
argued that an optimal capital structure can be obtained by trading off the
agency cost of debt against the benefit of debt as previously described.
Their second measure of agency cost is
a proxy for the loss in revenues attributable to inefficient asset utilization,
which can be taken as consequence of poor investment decisions or from
management’s shirking. They calculated agency costs as the ratio of annual
sales to total assets, an efficiency ratio. The result of Ang S. James et al.
(2000) is direct confirmation of the predictions made by Jensen and Meckling
(1976). Agency cost is higher among firms that are not 100 percent owned by
their mangers, and these costs increase as the equity share of the owner
manager declines. Hence, agency costs increase with a reduction in managerial
ownership, as predicted by Jensen and Meckling (1976).
Harris and Raviv (1991) referred to
various researcher that their model predict that leverage is positively
associated with firm value (Hirshleifer and Thakor (1989), Harris and Raviv
(1990a), Stulz (1990). Also, leverage is expected to be negatively associated
with the extent of growth opportunities (Jensen and Meckling, 1976) and (
Stulz, 1990).
No comments:
Post a Comment